‘6. The arbitral tribunal shall decide on the basis of the law, taking into account in particular though not exclusively:
- the law in force of the Contracting Party concerned;
- the provisions of this Agreement, and other relevant Agreements between the Contracting Parties;
- the provisions of special agreements relating to the investment:
- the general principles of international law.’
‘The arbitral tribunal shall decide on the basis of the law. When making its decision, the arbitral tribunal shall take into account, [in particular] though not exclusively, each of the four sources of law set out in Article 8.6. The arbitral tribunal must therefore take into account as far as they are relevant to the dispute the law in force of the Contracting Party concerned and the other sources of law set out in Article 8.6. To the extent that there is a conflict between national law and international law, the arbitral tribunal shall apply international law.’
1. Deciding Respondent has violated the following provisions of the Treaty:
a) The obligation of fair and equitable treatment (Art. 3(1);
b) The obligation not to impair the operation, management, maintenance, use, enjoyment or disposal of investments by unreasonable or discriminatory measures (Article 3(1);
c) The obligation of full security and protection (Art. 3(2)); and
d) The obligation to treat investments at least in conformity with the rules of international law (Art. 3(5)); and
e) The obligation not to deprive Claimant of its investment by direct or indirect measures (Art. 5); and...’
‘1. The Respondent has violated the following provisions of the Treaty:
a. The obligation of fair and equitable treatment (Article 3(1));
b. The obligation not to impair investments by unreasonable or discriminatory measures (Article 3 (1));
c. The obligation of full security and protection (Article 3 (2));
d. The obligation to treat foreign investments in conformity with principles of international law (Article 3 (5) and Article 8 (6), and
e. The obligation not to deprive Claimant of its investment (Article 5); and...’
‘2. Declaring that Respondent is obliged to remedy the injury that Claimant suffered as a result of Respondent’s violations of the Treaty by payment of the fair market value of Claimant’s investment in an amount to be determined at a second phase of this arbitration...’
‘2. The Respondent is obligated to remedy the injury the Claimant suffered as a result of Respondent’s violations of the Treaty by payment of the fair market value of Claimant’s investment as it was before consummation of the Respondent’s breach of Treaty in 1999 in an amount to be determined at a second phase of this arbitration;...’ (emphasis added)
‘Article 31
General rule of interpretation
1. A treaty shall be interpreted in good faith in accordance with the ordinary meaning to be given to the terms of the treaty in their context and in the light of its object and purpose.
2. The context for the purpose of interpretation of a treaty shall comprise, in addition to the text, including its preamble and annexes:
(a) any agreement relating to the treaty which was made between all the parties in connection with the conclusion of the treaty;
(b) any instrument which was made by one or more parties in connection with the conclusion of the treaty and accepted by the other parties as an instrument related to the treaty.
3. There shall be taken into account, together with the context:
(a) any subsequent agreement between the parties regarding the interpretation of the treaty or the application of its provisions;
(b) any subsequent practice in the application of the treaty which establishes the agreement of the parties regarding its interpretation;
(c) any relevant rules of international law applicable in the relations between the parties.
4. A special meaning shall be given to a term if it is established that the parties so intended.’
‘Article 32
Supplementary means of interpretation
Recourse may be had to supplementary means of interpretation, including the preparatory work of the treaty and the circumstances of its conclusion, in order to confirm the meaning resulting from the application of article 31, or to determine the meaning when the interpretation according to article 31:
(a) leaves the meaning ambiguous or obscure; or
(b) leads to a result which is manifestly absurd or unreasonable.
"... their determination to respect and put into practice, each of them in its relations with all other participating states, irrespective of their political economic or social systems, the principles laid out in the Final Act."
And the parties undertook that they:
"will respect each other’s sovereign equality and individuality...They will also respect each other’s right freely to choose and develop its political, social, economic and cultural systems...’
Thus the Helsinki Final Act context is not confined to that of investment protection; it had a wider purpose, which was the extension and intensification of economic relations between states parties particularly with respect to investments, and that process of extension is based on the mutual respect of states.
‘For the purposes of the present Agreement:
a) the term "investments" shall comprise every kind of asset invested either directly or through an investor of a third State and more particularly, though not exclusively:
(i) movable and immovable property and all related property rights;
(ii) shares, bonds and other kinds of interests in companies and
joint ventures, as well as rights derived therefrom;
(iii) title to money and other assets and to any performance having an economic value;
(iv) rights in the field of intellectual property, also including technical processes, goodwill and know-how;
(v) concessions conferred by law or under contract, including concessions to prospect, explore, extract and win natural resources.’
(a) Phelps Dodge Corp. v. Iran, 10 Iran - US CTR. 121 (1986), at paras. 24-31.
(b) Biloune v Ghana Investments Centre, 95 I.L.R. 184 (1990) at pp.228-9.
(c) Metalclad Corp v. United Mexican States. 119 I.L.R. 615 (2000), at pp.642-3, paras, 121-25’
‘Neither Contracting Party shall take any measures depriving, directly or indirectly, investors of the other Contracting Party of their investments unless the following conditions are complied with:
a) the measures are taken in the public interest and under due process of law;
b) the measures are not discriminatory;
c) the measures are accompanied by provision for the payment of just compensation. Such compensation shall represent the genuine value of the investments affected and shall, in order to be effective for the claimants, be paid and made transferable without undue delay to the country designated by the claimants concerned and in any freely convertible currency accepted by the claimants.’
‘1. Investments shall not be expropriated or nationalized either directly or indirectly through measures tantamount to expropriation or nationalization ("expropriation") except for a public purpose; in accordance with due process of law; in a non-discriminatory manner; upon payment of prompt, adequate and effective compensation; and in accordance with the general principles of treatment provided for in Article II (2).
Compensation shall be equivalent to the fair market value of the expropriated investment immediately before the expropriatory action was taken or became known; be paid without delay; include interest at a reasonable market rate from the date of expropriation; be fully realizable; and be freely transferable at the prevailing market rate of exchange on the date of expropriation.’
(Article III (1))
‘4. Nationalisation, expropriation or requisitioning shall be based on grounds or reasons of public utility, security or the national interest which are recognised as overriding purely individual or private interests, both domestic and foreign. In such case the owner shall be paid appropriate compensation, in accordance with the rules in force in the State taking such measures in the exercise of its sovereignty and in accordance with international law. In any case where the question of compensation gives rise to a controversy, the national jurisdiction of the State taking such measures shall be exhausted. However, upon agreement by sovereign States and other parties concerned, settlement of the dispute should be made through arbitration or international adjudication...’
’34. Mr. ALBEDA (Netherlands), whose country was a member of the Commission on Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources, said that it was evident, from the terms of the draft resolution, that its text constituted a balanced compromise between affirmation of the sovereign rights of national Governments over their natural resources and that of the desire to protect foreign interests according to the rules of international law. The draft, therefore, should be appreciated and welcomed by all the members of the Committee.
’35. Three main elements deserved equal attention. The first was the sovereign rights of States over the natural resources within their territories; it was the economic expression of the general principle of self-determination. That principle should be accepted by every State and by its nationals who invested their capital in another country. The time when foreign investment could be the first step to foreign domination had ended. The second principle was the need for international economic co-operation. It was based on the fact that, in many cases, full use of the existing natural resources for the benefit of all parties concerned was possible only if there was economic cooperation between sovereign nations. The third principle was that of strict adherence to the rules of international law and of the need for the consolidation and progressive development of those rules. That principle followed logically from the second one. If it was desired to eliminate the danger of foreign capital being the forerunner of foreign domination or of its being entirely at the mercy of the Government of its host country, strict adherence to the rules of international law was required.
’36. Those principles made it clear that substantial study of the draft resolution was not strictly within the competence of the Second Committee, but rather within that of the International Law Commission. It would perhaps not be wise for the Committee to start a debate and endeavour to change the text of the existing draft, since that would reopen the discussions which had been held in the Commission on Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources and would risk upsetting the balance of the existing text. The Committee therefore had the choice between accepting the draft resolution as it stood, without amendment, or repeating the debates that had taken place in the Commission on Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources. The Netherlands delegation thought that the first alternative would be the best procedure for the Committee to adopt.’
(Gen. Ass., Seventeenth Session, Second Committee, Agenda item 39, p.230)
For present purposes the leading principles of the Charter are to be found in
Article 2, as follows:
‘1. Every State has and shall freely exercise full permanent sovereignty including possession, use and disposal, over all its wealth, natural resources and economic activities.
‘2. Each State has the right:
(c) to nationalise, expropriate or transfer ownership of foreign property, in which case appropriate compensation should be paid by the State adopting such measures, taking into account its relevant laws and regulations and all circumstances that the State considers pertinent. In any case where the question of compensation gives rise to a controversy, it shall be settled under the domestic law of the nationalising State and by its tribunals, unless it is freely and mutually agreed by all States concerned that other peaceful means be sought on the basis of the sovereign equality of States and in accordance with the principle of free choice of means.’
‘The standard of "appropriate" compensation or its near-equivalents "just" and "equitable" compensation leaves considerable latitude to the parties in negotiation or to a third-party arbiter. In many cases, especially those involving a single property or investment, appropriate or just compensation would seem to require payment of "full market value" where that can be determined. The value of the enterprise as a "going concern" capitalising income may also be an appropriate standard subject to legitimate expectations and actual conditio ns. As some governments have maintained, it would not be inappropriate or unjust to reduce that amount where the company had valued a project at low figures to avoid taxation. Compensation settlements have used book value, sometimes "updated" to reflect inflation. In cases where the company had by practices contrary to good standards of operation, diminished the value of a natural resource, it would not be unjust for the government to reduce its compensation to make up for the damage. Payment in bonds may not be "prompt" under the Hull formula, but in many cases such deferred compensation would be appropriate and not unjust provided that the interest on the bonds was in keeping with market rates. Large-scale expropriation such as general land reform often raises questions as to ability of the State to pay full compensation. In such cases, a good case can be made that "less than full value would be just compensation" when the State would otherwise have "an overwhelming financial burden". (emphasis added) (International Law in Theory and Practice, Dordrecht, 1991, p.324).
First : the nature of an investment as a form of expenditure or transfer of funds for the precise purpose of obtaining a return.
Secondly: the element of reasonableness, which rules out the compensation of returns which go beyond the legitimate expectations of the investor.
Thirdly: the element which derives from the general principle that merely speculative benefits, based upon unproven economic projections, do not count as investment or as returns.
‘146. But as regards States which welcome foreign investment, and which even engage in it themselves, it could be expected that their attitude towards compensation should not be such as to render foreign investment useless, economically. In this respect it is not disputed that Kuwait is a country favouring foreign investment, and itself an important investor abroad. The Tribunal does not intend either to examine, or resolve the complex of juridical problems created by the fact that there are some States that are motivated by very different sets of conceptions about foreign investment, possibly involving within the framework of the international community what the International Court of Justice has called an "intense conflict of systems and interests" (Barcelona Traction, etc., case, I.C.J. Reports, 1970, p.47, paragraph 89). The Tribunal will therefore confine itself to registering that in the case of the present dispute there is no room for rules of compensation that would make nonsense of foreign investment.
‘147. This is a fundamental precept. It is pertinent during the life-time of a concession; it is equally pertinent when a concession comes to an end. Compensation then, must be calculated on a basis such as to warrant the upkeep of a flow of investment in the future.
‘148. Both Parties to the present litigation have invoked the notion of "legitimate expectations" for deciding on compensation. That formula is well-advised, and justifiably brings to mind the fact that, with reference to every long-term contract, especially such as involve an important investment, there must necessarily be economic calculations, and the weighing-up of rights and obligations, of chances and risks, constituting the contractual eguilibrium. This equilibrium cannot be neglected - neither when it is a question of proceeding to necessary adaptations during the course of the contract, nor when it is a question of awarding compensation. It is in this fundamental equilibrium that the very essence of the contract consists.
‘149. For assessment of that equilibrium itself, and of the legitimate expectations to which it gives rise, it is above all the text of the contract that signifies, and it is of moment that this text should be precise and exhaustive. But it is not only a question of the original text; there are also the amendments, the interpretations and the behaviour manifested along the course of its existence, that indicate (often fortuitously) how the legitimate expectations of the Parties are to be seen, and sometimes seen as becoming modified according to the circumstances.
‘150. It is on the footing of these general principles that the Tribunal will now enquire into the circumstances specific to the case of Aminoil.
[..... ]
‘154. The two basic points on which the Tribunal differs from Aminoil’s position are as follows:
(a) First, in respect of the foundation for the calculation of anticipated profits, which Aminoil takes as being exclusively the financial arrangements of 1961, the Tribunal has already found in Section IV above, both that the 1973 Agreements were valid, and that something is owing to the Government on Abu Dhabi account. Not only is no refund due of moneys paid to the Government under the 1973 arrangements, but the latter are also a component of the present "legitimate expectations" of the Company. Even more pertinent, the negotiations between the Parties about the application of the Abu Dhabi Formula involved a recognition of the principle of a monetary obligation to the Government, and of a modification for the future of the financial relations of the Parties. It is therefore on a combination of these data, not on those of 1961, that the indemnification of the Company must be proceeded to.
(b) Next - and this constitutes the second aspect of the difference between the Tribunal’s and Aminoil’s positions - the Tribunal cannot accept the projections as to the future of the petroleum industry based on the consultations of experts that the Company has relied upon. These have been criticized by the Government. If, however, the Tribunal does not accept them, this is not because they include speculative elements, since all methods of assessment, whatever they may be, will do that. It is because the Tribunal thinks that in the present case, as will be shown later, the Parties adopted a different conception in the course of their relations and negotiations, - namely that of the reasonable rate of return. This it is, therefore, that must guide the Tribunal.’ (emphasis added)
(66 ILR. at pp.602-5)
1. Exh. RQ 13, dated 1 August 1996 : Agreement on a Future Agreement to Transfer CNTS Participation Interests and CET 21 Shares.
2. Exh. RQ 18, dated 1 August 1996: Agreement on a Future Agreement to Transfer CET 21 Shares.
3. Exh. RQ 19, dated 1 August 1996: Agreement on a Future Agreement to Transfer CET 21 Participation Interests.
1. Klinkhammer’s Suppl. Declaration on Quantum, para. 54.
2. Agreement on Transfer of Participation Interest, 17 July 1996, Art. II : Exh. CQ. 80.
3. Memorandum of Association and Investment Agreement, Art. 1.4.3(a); Exh.C.60.
COMPETITION
‘Excluding Germany, the level of competition in CME’s markets is low. In addition, CME’s competitive position in each market is strengthened by strong local partners and relationships. CME’s solid position financially, its control of content and programming, and its relationships with advertisers is hard to beat. Supported by an enviable track record, CME is a well respected media player and a desirable partner in these markets. Still, some investors worry about how the Company will progress when faced with real competition in the future. Comments included, "This is as close to a monopoly as you can get;" "I don’t see how much longer they can get away with monopolizing the market."'
(Exh. RQ 377, at page 14)
‘Q. When you use the term "dominant player", what would you describe as some of the characteristics of a dominant television company in a market place?
‘A. It is really the ability to set price, because the advertiser cannot buy around you. So, that would mean that you would have to have somewhere around a 40/45 per cent commercial share in order to be a dominant player because anything less the advertiser can buy around you.
‘Q. Can you identify some of the competitive advantages of being a dominant player?
‘A. Well, that is the ability - there is the ability to set price. There is the ability to conclude exclusive arrangements with advertisers where you can insist that as a condition of doing business with you they do not do business with your competitor.
You can - you are making more money so you can afford to control programming, deny smaller stations access to programming. You can buy the talent. By the talent I mean the television hosts and the newscasters that are most appealing to the audience. You can actually go out and raid the other station’s talent, pick off the talent. Those would be some of the things a dominant player can and will do.’
(Transcript, Day 11, pp.233-4)
‘The CME forecast’s relatively lower operating margins in 1999 through 2002 result from an aggressive increase in operating expenses forecasted for 1999. That Monitor margins somewhat exceed CME’s during portions of the forecast period is a function of Monitor’s lower inflation expectations and CME’s higher depreciation charges. While CNTS’s projected operating margins are high, we believe they are warranted given CNTS’s dominant position as the advertising medium of choice in an oligopolistic market with little competitive threat.’
(CNTS Valuation Report, p.10)
‘That TV Nova’s ad revenues have outpaced even Monitor’s projections is particularly remarkable in light of the damage to TV Nova’s audience share that is directly attributable to the termination of CNTS’s involvement with TV Nova. When CET 21 terminated its contract with CNTS, TV Nova immediately lost access to CNTS’s vast library of high-quality programming. The resulting drop in program quality caused an immediate loss of 10 audience share points, from which TV Nova has not recovered. As shown in Exhibit CQ2 (at 4), during the year preceding August, 1999, TV Nova’s audience share remained stable in the low-to mid-fifties. In August 1999, TV Nova’s audience share dropped to 46.8 and stabilized immediately in the mid-forties. That TV Nova was able to exceed Monitor’s ad revenue projections despite this substantial loss of audience share further demonstrates both the conservatism of Monitor’s revenue projections and the Czech market’s unique economics that have continued to confer monopolistic rewards on the dominant player even after a substantial reduction in audience share.’
(Supplemental Report, pp.17-18)
First : that the host State is not accepting a risk which will have the consequence of paying compensation at a level which would cause catastrophic economic consequences for the host State and its population.
Second : that an investment carries the expectation that it will be profitable, but only on a basis of reasonable expectations.
Third : that explicit indications of the investor’s expectation of profitability will provide a primary criterion of what is a reasonable rate of return.
A. ‘In October 1991, I was approached by Mr. Andrew Gaspar, a partner of Mr. Ronald Lauder in Central European Development Corporation (CEDC), and engaged as a consultant to investigate and review television opportunities for CEDC in post-communist Europe. My work for CEDC was directed by Mr. Mark Palmer, its Managing Director who was based in Berlin, and was performed through The Acorn Consulting Group, Inc., a New York Corporation owned by Victoria A.L. Rogers and myself.
B. I continued in the above consulting capacity until the inception of Central European Media Enterprises Ltd. (CME) in June 1994 when I became Vice President and Chief Financial Officer of CME.
C. During the calendar year 1993 and the first half of 1994 I moved from New York to Europe at the behest of CEDC. I lived halftime in Prague and was involved on a day-to-day basis with the planning and launch of Nova. In June 1994, I moved to the new London headquarters of CME and my focus shifted to the seeking of television licenses in other countries and the management of CME.
D. In August 1995 I was named President and Chief Executive Officer of CME in which position I remained until March 1998.’
(Declaration dated 7 December 2000)
‘This memo is to record what I can recall we learned at the hearing today and document what we told the Commission which we may need to remember in the future.
‘1. Other Partners: The Commission asked if we had any other partners involved in the CET 21 investment. You responded that at this time we were doing the investment ourselves, with the exception of the Czech Savings Bank which was described by Vladimir Zelezny. You also told them that we were open to additional Czech partners, provided that we were satisfied that we knew who they represented.
Korte said that the Commission does not want to be involved in the selection of our partners and will keep their hands off; they just wanted to know who was involved in our investment.
‘We expressed our concern that if there were additional partners the station have a single management, single board, etc. Mr. Korte, speaking for the committee agreed and said it was the only way the station could work.
‘2. They asked how much we were prepared to invest. We responded that our business plan showed a requirement of 500-600 million Czech crowns - or $18-21 million - however, we recognized that sometimes additional funding is needed and we were willing to commit up to 1 billion crowns ($36 million) of our own money plus the 300 million from the Czech bank for a total of 1.3 billion KCS. They asked whether the technical rebuild of the transmission network was included in the 600 million figure, and I said it was not since we did not have a clear picture of the technical situation with F1 and CTV.’
[............]
‘5. The Council asked for our business plan, and we agreed to give it to them by the end of next week. They said it must be the same plan which we use for the bank and other investors (i.e. one set of numbers).’
(emphasis added)
‘Dear members of the Council,
‘In accordance with our promise, which was made at the last hearing, we are sending you the business plan for our television station as it was proposed by the investors and approved by our administrative board. It is an extract from a detailed breakdown of the individual technical items.
‘We expect that the basic initial capital will be CZK 1 billion 300 million (as follows from sheet 1 - Financial Summary). In accordance with the international practice, the numbers in brackets stand for the planned loss, and not profit, and, therefore, a minus could be added in front of the numbers. It is apparent that the first active income of CET 21 is expected in 1997 and redemption of the basic investments only after 2000. In the first four years of operation, the business plan anticipates a direct loss that will have to be funded by the investors.
‘The business plan has already been adjusted for the licensed station F-1 (with a variant of CTV). If you have any queries, we will respond to them at any time in writing or at the next hearing.’
Yours faithfully
[signature]
In Prague, on 13 January 1993 Administrative Board of CET 21
‘If one then looks at how the numbers work out over the page, the CET 21 business plan shows first of all, as one would expect in 1993, nil anticipated revenues, expenses at 22 million Crowns and a net loss deficit, therefore, of 22 million, capital expenditure of 100 million Crowns, networking capital needs of 119 million. Therefore a net operating deficit cashflow of 241 - the amount of the investment at 250 million with available capital there. It then works through, and as you can see, one does not get to a positive cashflow in terms of net operating cashflow until in fact the year 1998, and one does not get to a cumulative cashflow which is positive until the year 2001.
‘That is then supported by the figures which are set out following, which set out what they then anticipated about revenues based on the average number of homes using the TV, weighted audiences and so on and so forth. In other words the next pages really provide what they then anticipated. If one looks forward, one sees that one has anticipated expenses and so on and so forth.
‘We have summarised those figures at paragraph 5 of appendix 18. What one sees there is the figures converted into million dollars set out, and one sees the equity assumptions being provided as $28.2 million, and one sees the revenues over the ten-year period of the plan being anticipated to be 65.7.
‘So you have a total net profit of $65.7 million, compared with equity of $28.2 million. That amounts to a total pre-tax return of 232 per cent and over the nine full years our calculation is a average annual return of 26.9, take off tax at 35 per cent and you have a post-tax average return of 16.8 per cent.’
(Transcript, Day 23, pp.214-15; and see also Respondent’s Skeleton Closing Submissions. App. 18)
‘In printed media in the Czech Republic complete business liberty for home and foreign subjects is guaranteed and the publishing has no administrative obstructions. Possible evaluation of the dominant position on printed media market belongs to the competency of the concerned authority (The authority for protection of economic competition).
‘In electronic media the situation is a bit different: Plurality of the broadcasting subject is to a certain extent limited physically (by frequencies). There is a limited number of terrestrially broadcasted television programs. Each businessman gets, by the granting of nation-wide terrestrial television to an exceptional position. With contemporary advertising limits for public service TV and factual impossibility of building the equal commercial competition the granting of former "federal nation-wide television channel" was in fact a warrant of almost certain profit even with average business abilities and minimum initial investments.
‘When government grants the businessman the freguency network (= an exclusive part of national possession, "the gold mine"), it should naturally want something from the businessman for that, and this is usually common all over the world.
‘The argument, that the businessman pays profit taxes does not stand up, because it is completely extraordinary profit from completely extraordinary kind of enterprise. Besides even back in the Middle Ages wise governor established special taxes for some profitable kinds of enterprise or gave concessions to his favorites (for mining metals, changing money in good localities, etc.).’
(Exh. RQ 38, English version, p.6; emphasis in the original).
‘124. We know from Len Fertig’s business plan that CEDC anticipated an aggregate net profit of US$65.7 million over the period 1993 to 2002 on an assumed equity investment of US$28.2 million. This established an expected rate of return of 16.8%. The Czech Republic accepts this as a reasonable and fair rate of return on the investment.
‘125. Mr Lauder’s various companies invested the following amounts (not the $140 million asserted by Mr Klinkhammer):
(a) $3 million by CEDC in 1993 in respect of the setting up of CNTS;
(b) $5.7 million of assets in-kind by CEDC in 1994;
(c) $5.2 million by CME Media in 1996 representing the price paid to CET 21 partners in respect of 43.3% of CET 21 and 5.2% of CNTS;
(d) $37 million by CME Media in 1996 representing the price paid to Czech Savings Bank in respect of 22% of CNTS; and
(e) $28.3 million by CME Media in 1997 representing the price paid to Nova Consulting in respect of 5.8% of CNTS.
‘126. Thus, the maximum possible investment made by CME Ltd was $78 million. (The purchase of the 5.8% shareholding for $28 million has now been rescinded pursuant to the ICC Award, reducing the aggregate investment to $49.3 million.)
‘127. Applying the post-tax rate of return of 16.8% per annum to CME Ltd’s actual investments in CNTS, from the original date of investment to (say) 31 December 2002, results in the a total gross return on the investment of $184.3 million.
‘128. From this figure, it is necessary to deduct:
(a) the dividends received by CME (and its predecessors) of $34.7 million;
(b) the amount received from Dr Zelezny in payment of the ICC award of at least $23.35 million; and
(c) 93.2% of the residual value (of US$57.7 million), namely US$53.8m.
‘129. Accordingly, the maximum net further amount of compensation that would be needed to realise in full the expectations with which Mr Lauder and the Czech Republic first embarked upon the investment would be $72.4 million.’
(Respondent’s Skeleton of Closing Submissions, pp.27-8).
‘238. As a projection into the future, any cash flow projection has an element of speculation associated with it, as recognised by the Claimant. For this very reason it is disputable whether a tribunal can use it at all for the valuation of compensation. One of the best settled rules of the law of international responsibility of States is that no reparation for speculative or uncertain damage can be awarded. This holds true of the existence of the damage and of its effect as well. Such a rule, therefore, applies in the case of unlawful expropriation. A fortiori, the reasoning on which it rests must also apply in the case of compensation for a lawful expropriation. It does not permit the use of a method which yields uncertain figures for the valuation of damages, even if the existence of damages is certain.
‘239. The element of speculation in a short-term projection is rather limited, although unexpected events can make it turn out to be wrong. The speculative element rapidly increases with the number of years to which a projection relates. It is well known, and certainly taken into account by investors, that if it applies to a rather distant future a projection is almost purely speculative, even if it is done by the most serious and experienced forecasting firms, especially if it relates to such a volatile factor as oil prices. Such projections can be useful indications for a prospective investor, who understands how far it can rely on them and accepts the risks associated with them; they certainly cannot be used by a tribunal as the measure of a fair compensation.
‘240. The projection of the future earnings of Khemco over 18 years was made by the Claimant in order to take into account the totality of the return which could be derived from the Khemco Agreement for the remaining time of its life. Clearly, this is a consequence of the Claimant’s misconception that the measure of the compensation is restitutio in integrum. A case of expropriation of an undertaking with no contractual limit would, under this reasoning, require a projection into the future ad infinitum, or, to be more precise, up to the time when the application of the discount rate would result in a return amounting to nil. The Tribunal need not express an opinion upon the admissibility of such a projection when the reparation must wipe out all the consequences of an illegal taking, but it certainly cannot accept it for the compensation due in case of a lawful expropriation.’
(15 lran-U.S.C.T.R.189, at pp.262-3) (and see also at page 257, para 225 in fine).
’13. The International Law Commission, after a careful study of the matter, asserted that "[t]ribunals have been reluctant to provide compensation for claims with inherently speculative elements." The Czech Republic submits that the value of an element is speculative if the realisation of the value is entirely out of the control of the investor and entirely under the control of some other party.
’14. In the present case, the clearest example of such a speculative element is CME’s attempt to include in the valuation of CNTS a sum corresponding to the possibility that the Czech authorities might renew, on the same terms as were applied in 1993, CET 21’s broadcasting licence when it expired in 2005.
’15. Neither CET 21 nor CME had any right to any renewal of the Licence. CME failed to demonstrate that there is any presumption in Czech law, or in public international law, in favour of renewal of the Licence. CME adduced no evidence that it had been led by any official or employee of the Czech Republic to believe that the Licence would be renewed.
’16. CME did not allege that it had any legitimate expectation, enforceable under the Dutch Treaty or under Czech law, to the renewal of the Licence. But if compensation were awarded for post 2005 profits expected to arise from TV Nova, that would be tantamount to a finding that the Czech Republic was under a legal obligation to permit CNTS to collect those profits by renewing CET 21’s Licence.
’17. Even less was there any basis for a belief that the Licence would be renewed on the same terms as were applied in 1993. CNTS was well aware of the complaints that had been made concerning the manner in which TV Nova was being operated. It was aware of concerns about the "Call the Director" programme; of concerns relating to the down-market content of TV Nova programmes; and of concerns that CET 21 was not in fact discharging the responsibilities imposed by law upon the holder of the Licence. In those circumstances, it is difficult to see what basis CNTS might have to suppose that CET 21 would simply have its Licence renewed. The possibility of renewal on more exacting, and accordingly less profitable, terms must have been apparent to CME.
18. CME was well aware of the risk of non-renewal of the Licence. As senior management acknowledged in a revised peace offer made to Dr Zelezny in early March 1999:
"Without a closer alignment of economic interests and a stronger Service Agreement, we believe that it will not be possible to ‘sleep at night’... The term sheet provides considerable cash incentives to VZ, but the biggest payout occurs after the renewal and over four years, thereby rewarding success and sharing the risk."
’19. The hopes of a licence renewal were not a bankable asset. There was, on the other hand, a clear possibility of renewal. It was a commercial judgment whether that possibility warranted further investment in the company or the purchase of the company. But in the submission of the Czech Republic, the fact that this possibility was worth a commercial gamble on the part of CNTS or SBS does not mean that it must be counted in the computation of the "genuine value" of CNTS, as explained further below in Appendix XV.’
‘Desiring to extend and intensify the economic relations between them particularly with respect to investments by the investors of one Contracting Party in the territory of the other Contracting Party.
‘Recognising that agreement upon the treatment to be accorded to such investments will stimulate the flow of capital and technology and the economic development of the Contracting Parties and that fair and equitable treatment is desirable.
‘Taking note of the Final Act of the Conference on Security and Cooperation in Europe, signed on August, 1st 1975 in Helsinki. ‘Have agreed as follows:...’
‘It is, therefore, in the Chamber’s view, evident that the respective scale of activities connected with fishing - or navigation, defence or, for that matter, petroleum exploration and exploitation - cannot be taken into account as a relevant circumstance or, if the term is preferred, as an equitable criterion to be applied in determining the delimitation line. What the Chamber would regard as a legitimate scruple lies rather in concern lest the overall result, even though achieved through the application of equitable criteria and the use of appropriate methods for giving them concrete effect, should unexpectedly be revealed as radically inequitable, that is to say, as likely to entail catastrophic repercussions for the livelihood and economic well-being of the population of the countries concerned.’
(I.C.J. Reports, 1984, p.342, para. 237).
‘(a) It is recognised that Japan should pay reparations to the Allied Powers for the damage and suffering caused by it during the war. Nevertheless it is also recognised that the resources of Japan are not presently sufficient if it is to maintain a viable economy, to make complete reparation for all such damage and suffering and at the same time meet its obligations.’
‘You also know, because you have been told on several occasions, that the Czech Republic has a population of 10 million, and in our closing submissions we give the gross national income of the Czech Republic of $5,270 per head. What we have done there is simply set out what the equivalent claims would be against each of the countries represented by the distinguished members of this arbitral tribunal. What we have done -- so that there is no dispute about it - is multiplied first of all to take account of the population. So that in the case of United Kingdom, we multiply by 6 to take account of the fact that the United Kingdom is 6 times the size of the Czech Republic. We have then taken account of the differential in gross national income per head by dividing by 5,270 and multiplying by 24,230. I should make it plain that these are figures in dollars, of course.
So that you get a claim equivalent to that brought against the Czech Republic against the United Kingdom of 19.3 billion dollars.
In Germany’s case, of course, it has a larger population. It has a slightly lower gross national income per head which, of course, followed the reunification and the accretion of what used to be East Germany. But it amounts to an equivalent claim against Germany of just under $26 billion.
And the figures for the USA, which of course has a substantially larger population, and a substantially larger gross national income per head, would mean a claim of 131 billion dollars, if this were being brought against the United States.
That is how important this case is to the Czech Republic and I am sure each of you can well imagine the sort of political, economic and decision-making difficulties which would be faced when that sort of claim was brought under one of these treaties against your states.’ (DAY 23, p.62)
‘Rothschild’s approach appears to be consistent with that adopted by SBS Broadcasting and CME Ltd. SBS also used a discount of 20% in its valuation of CNTS. David Stogel uses a 20% discount (in Declarations Representing Quantum of Claimant CME Czech Republic BV, tab 4, no. 10). Woody Knight likewise, states in a memo:
"we assumed that a higher risk, Eastern European operator, CME Ltd’s private market multiple would be at a 15-25% discount to the corresponding SBS multiples." ‘
‘c. Price of peace in Czech Republic equal to approximately USD 100 million...’
‘c. Price of peace in Czech Republic equal to approximately USD125 million, comprised of:
18% of CNTS (estimated value USD 400 million) = USD 72 million
Zelezny annuity for license renewal = USD 27 million
4% fee for CET21 of which approximately USD 3.2 million per year is unrecoverable, using 8x multiple value equal to approximately USD 25 million’
3.4 IMPLIED CNTS VALUE
Applying a 15% liquidity discount to the nominal value of the Final SBS Offer, CNTS’ implied value is derived in the following table:
Table 3.3.3 - CNTS value implied by SBS Final Offer
US$m | |
Offer value (nominal) | 374 |
15% Discount | (56) |
Net value of CME | 318 |
Add: net debt | 134 |
Enterprise value of CME | 452 |
Comprising: | |
Corporate expenses | (51)-(33) |
Value of non-CNTS assets | 207-259 |
Implied value of CNTS | 296-226 |
On this basis, the implicit value of CNTS represents between 50% and 65% of CME Ltd.’s enterprise value before adjusting for the value of corporate expenses. This is consistent with statements that we understand were made to investors by SBS management in connection with the Final SBS Offer.’
(Report, page 68)
‘The DCF method estimates a company’s value based on the current value of its forecasted cashflows. As Monitor correctly notes, DCF is generally accepted by mergers and acquisitions practitioners as a leading method to value a company as a going concern. Any company is said to be "worth" the net present value of its future cash earnings stream taken out to infinity and discounted at a rate that approximates the risk.’ (at page 18).
(1) Investments, including retained profits: 84 million dollars.
(2) Foreseeable profits (Len Fertig’s Business Plan): Period 1993-2002: profits of 65.7 million dollars + extrapolated to the end of 2005: add 19.71 million: total is 85.41 million + subject to (3) below.
(3) Dominant position: treaty-based discount factor of ten per cent of the total profit equals 76.87 million dollars.
Already registered ?